Electric
bills hide turmoil in the electric industry.
Some
recent events illustrate the point. The Maine Legislature sustained
Gov. LePage’s veto of solar power subsidies. Renewable subsidies
are pushing up costs. New transmission lines are raising rates.
Major Canadian hydro projects, hoping for U.S. markets, experience
runaway costs
Policy
decisions contribute to hidden increases in the price of power. In
short, the electric bill pays for more than economical, reliable
power.
Back
in 1993, Congress remodeled the industry. Formerly, utilities owned
both power generators and all the wires, used to serve captive
customers. Then Congress ruled transmission lines had to carry any
producers’ power, not just that from the line-owners.
In
many states, including Maine, utilities were forced to sell off their
generators, becoming solely wires companies. The risk of costly,
faulty power supply decisions was moved from their customers to
independent power suppliers.
The
goal was competition among suppliers in a reasonably open market.
That worked and the customer’s cost of power may have fallen by
about one-third, particularly for those sticking with the standard or
default offer.
That’s
the good news. The not-so-good news was that the cost of wires just
about doubled, allowing the traditional utilities to thrive with
little risk.
Wires
costs rose because utilities convinced regulators that their
transmission lines were old and needed replacement, not always the
case.
Siting
of new generators also boosted costs. Traditionally, to keep
transmission costs low, generators were located close to big markets.
But such siting became increasingly difficult.
Some
thought that cheap power could be imported from Canada, avoiding
siting problems. But that power wouldn’t be any less costly than
prices set in the U.S. market where it would be sold. And production
costs in Canada are rising.
Public
policy encourages renewable resources like hydro, solar and wind.
Costly lines from new, distant generators to urban customers may be
necessary. That could be the result of recent proposals to generate
power in Maine for use in Massachusetts.
But
government ordered regulators to go even further. Renewable power
could be expensive to produce, slowing its development. Regulators
were required to build subsidies into electric rates to allow
renewables to appear to be competitive with traditional fuels like
coal and oil.
Higher
costs paid by today’s customers would supposedly produce cleaner
and less costly power for tomorrow’s customers. That’s been
promised for decades with dubious results.
Regulators
forecast future electricity costs and then price renewables in line
with their predictions. The problem is they usually get their
forecasts wrong. For example, today’s natural gas prices are far
below what they foresaw. Plus, there are new wires costs.
Customers
pay a premium price to subsidize renewables without gaining an
immediate economic benefit. That’s a real problem for Maine, the
poorest state in New England and one struggling to attract new
industry.
When
the Legislature fell short of the votes to override Gov. LePage’s
veto of solar subsidies, it aided customers. The veto may have
slowed solar development from becoming competitive and improving the
state’s energy mix, but it kept the subsidy’s direct and indirect
effects out of current rates.
Renewables
deserve public support, but why should today’s customers be forced
to pay the subsidy? If regulators were limited to setting rates only
for reliable service, legislators could set public policy and
subsidize renewables with tax revenues, not rates. Trying to finance
subsidies by taxes could reveal if voters favor such support.
By
shifting subsidies into electric rates, government levies hidden
taxes. It’s public policy without public responsibility. But it
can hurt low-income customers and discourage some industries from
locating in a high-cost market. On this one, LePage is correct.
Utilities
will soon face paying the costs of underused utility lines, as more
local resources are developed to serve local users. That’s called
“distributed generation,” and it is likely the wave of the
future. With improved batteries and other power storage, smaller
local solar and wind mini-grids will be possible.
Utilities
may stop growing, if new lines are not needed. While they will be
allowed to cover their costs, their profits might suffer. They will
expect customers to cover expected profits.
The
solution could be to allow utilities to become developers of
small-scale, renewable generators. Waning profits from big wires
projects could be gradually offset by local power systems.
The
cost of electricity reflects policy decisions about what resources we
use, where they are located and what we pay for them. The monthly
bill hides all that.
(Disclosure:
I was Maine’s first Public Advocate and headed the state energy
office.)
No comments:
Post a Comment