Do government programs to encourage job creation work or do
they merely guarantee corporate profits?
Nobody knows the answer with certainty, but there’s evidence
corporations promote development subsidies more to boost their profits than to
create new jobs.
The mantra of most politicians is “jobs, jobs, jobs.” But many of them oppose direct government
hiring or projects that will require government contractors to hire more
workers.
Indirect corporate support is appealing, because it seems to
have no cost for taxpayers. The benefits
are supposed to flow through the business and end up in employee paychecks and
corporate profits.
Often government support for business development is offered
through extremely complicated programs.
One reason for the complexity is reliance on tax breaks, which can obscure
where the benefits really go.
Congress and state legislatures are convinced to enact
indirect development measures without a full understanding of how they really
play out. Corporations can sell them based
on the possible job gains, which sound politically appealing, without revealing
the loopholes from which they expect to benefit.
Legislators believe that, if business prospers, new jobs
will inevitably develop. In that way,
two objectives are met: job creation and allowing the private sector, rather
than government, to shape economic priorities.
That’s consistent with a free enterprise economy and limited government.
Corporate incentives also have a clear political
benefit. As noted, they are offered
without any apparent cost to taxpayers.
There’s no appropriation of public money though they receive support funded
by tax revenues. The flow of money from the
taxpayer through the budget to the subsidy is too difficult to track.
Businesses like indirect support programs; their profits are
virtually guaranteed even though job creation is not. Corporate beneficiaries often turn up as
political contributors, providing legislators with their own incentive for offering
indirect support for business development.
The New Markets Capital Investment program, recently revealed
by the Maine Sunday Telegram, rings all the warning bells of an indirect
program.
Through gimmicks created by the corporations involved but not
understood by the legislators, some of whom had received political
contributions from those companies, investors will receive about $16 million
from the state on a supposed $40 million investment, of which not a penny will have
gone to creating jobs.
Instead of believing promises that a public indirect
investment will be more than compensated by expected employment gains and
resulting added tax revenues, legislators ought to regard the cost of any
indirect program as an outright expenditure.
Besides, state business-boosting programs are essentially
“beggar thy neighbor” measures. They are
intended to enable one state to pick up investment and jobs that might go to
another state. It’s not a competitive
advantage that matters; it’s the gimmick.
At the federal level, Congress does much the same thing,
willingly offering indirect corporate breaks while rejecting direct action. It readily adopts tax breaks for the private sector,
passing the resulting unpaid cost of government on to average taxpayers, while
rejecting funds for roads and bridges, left to deteriorate.
Perhaps the central problem of both the federal and state governments
in accepting such programs is the lack of an economic vision. A mere commitment to “jobs, jobs, jobs” is not
good enough for judging the value of proposed publicly supported programs.
A state with a coherent and consistent policy, not merely “special”
job creation incentives, can prosper.
Texas, with its emphasis on little regulation and both major parties
pro-business, has boomed. New Hampshire
consistently avoids a state income tax, and its economy has grown.
Maine places a higher priority on the environment. Some investors, from renewable energy to
tourism, can accept and prosper under a strong environmental regime.
But the state fails to offer a consistent outlook to
businesses. Tax reform and a stable
economic and social policy could be more effective than risky trade-offs
tailored for specific companies.
The Maine Legislature signed onto an investment gimmick it
did not understand in the mere hope of creating jobs. At about the same time, it was willing
effectively to expel one of the largest companies in the world that had already
committed to a major renewable energy investment in the state.
The misguided New Markets tax refund program adopted by the
Legislature had no chance of replacing the lost opportunity caused by breaking
a deal, not involving tax dollars, with energy giant Statoil for off-shore wind
energy.
Keeping policies consistent, uncomplicated and fair could
produce better results with fewer chances for programs to backfire. Such policies plus more direct economic support
by government would likely produce more jobs.
No comments:
Post a Comment